Page 222 - ES 2020-21_Volume-1-2 [28-01-21]
P. 222

Regulatory Forbearance: An Emergency Medicine, Not Staple Diet!  205


             7.3  During  the  period  of  the  global  financial  crisis  (GFC),  the  policy  worked  well  with
             banks selecting genuinely distressed, but viable in the long-run, borrowers for restructuring.
             Box 3 explains the careful panel regressions undertaken to control for various confounding
             factors. The results show that, during the GFC, banks more likely to benefit from forbearance
             do  not  differ  in  their  selection  of  restructuring  choices  when  compared  to  a  bank  with  a
             lower likelihood of utilizing forbearance. The propensity to restructure any given borrower,
             including  unviable  ones  is,  however,  significantly  higher  in  the  years  after  the  crisis.
             Evidently,  once  the  banks  got  a  signal  about  the  continuation  of  forbearance  despite  the
             economic recovery, several types of distortions crept in. As pointed out earlier, emergency
             medicine indeed became a staple diet. For instance, figures 6 and 7 show that the proportions
             of loans restructured increased significantly during this period. The share of restructured loans
             increased from 0.74% in FY2008 to 6.94% in FY2015, as shown in figure 6. The increase in
             the share of restructured loans among public sector banks was much higher, from 0.82% to
             8.49%. However, the private sector banks also saw their share of restructured loans increase
             from 0.64% to 2.87%. On the contrary, as shown in figure 8, the reported gross NPAs of banks
             increased only modestly from 2.2% in FY2008 to 4.3% in FY2015. It appears that the banks
             used the option of restructuring loans that were on the verge of defaulting without regard to
             the viability of such loans, as shown subsequently in Section 8.27. During the forbearance
             window, the proportion of firms in default increased by 51% after their loan(s) got restructured.
             In the pre-forbearance era, there was only a marginal 6% increase in the likelihood of defaults
             after restructuring. Forbearance thus helped banks to hide a lot of bad loans.


                             Box 3: Difference-in-Difference Framework to Show
                                          Distortion in Banks’ Incentives
                Mannil, Nishesh, and Tantri (2020) use a difference-in-difference methodology to test whether
                and when forbearance induces lending distortions among banks. This strategy estimates the
                lending activity by a bank in the counterfactual scenario of forbearance not being available.
                The difference in the actual lending activity in the presence of forbearance and the one under
                this counterfactual scenario is therefore a consequence of forbearance.

                To this end, banks are classified into two separate groups - B1 and B2, such that the two types
                of banks are similar in all respects except for their susceptibility to exploiting the forbearance
                policies. Precisely, banks in B1 have a higher proportion of borrowers that are adversely hit
                by the crisis. This naturally increases the likelihood of B1, relatively, exploiting the use of
                regulatory forbearance measures. By a thorough comparison of attributes such as ownership,
                capital, NPA, and age, Mannil, Nishesh, and Tantri (2020) show that the two categories of
                banks thus formed are otherwise similar.
                Banks in B1, o n average, would have a higher share of loans restructured during the crisis
                on account of the higher shock faced by their borrowers. Therefore, a comparison of B1 and
                B2 on aggregate outcomes would not be appropriate to understand the distortions forbearance
                can induce. Subsequently, Mannil, Nishesh, and Tantri (2020) use a firm-level fixed effects
                estimate that compares outcomes within a given firm and between the two types of banks.
                If for the same firm, banks in B1 exhibit a higher restructuring activity during forbearance,
                it  implies  that  these  banks,  on  average,  are  relatively  less  prudent  in  selecting  cases  for
                restructuring and are likely to restructure even unviable projects. Because B1 and B2 are
   217   218   219   220   221   222   223   224   225   226   227