Page 218 - ES 2020-21_Volume-1-2 [28-01-21]
P. 218

Regulatory Forbearance: An Emergency Medicine, Not Staple Diet!  201



                 2.  If the project is unviable, the bank would  2.  Capital-starved  banks  now  have  an
                    not restructure the loan and declare the    incentive to restructure even unviable
                    asset  as  non-performing.  Crucially,      projects  to  reduce  provisioning  and
                    banks  do  not  gain  by  restructuring     avoid the consequent hit on capital.
                    unviable projects in this case.


                Absent  forbearance,  a  bank  must  decide  to  restructure  based  on  the  viability  of  the
                firm/project because the cost of restructuring an unviable firm is significant. But, with
                forbearance, banks do not suffer any near-term cost from restructuring. Therefore, banks
                prefer restructuring, as this choice allows them to declare fewer NPAs and avoid the
                costs  due  to  loan  provisioning.  Forbearance  thus  incentivizes  banks  to  take  risks  by
                restructuring stressed assets even if they are unviable. Capital-constrained entities are
                particularly susceptible to investing in risky projects, a phenomenon called risk-shifting
                in academic literature (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Consider the case where a bank has
                a large outstanding against a borrower who is on the verge of default. If the borrower
                defaults, the bank would have to recognize the debt as NPA, incur a loss, and possibly
                re-capitalize on account of the depleted capital. Given the borrower’s solvency concerns,
                lending a fresh loan, or restructuring its current loan(s) is extremely risky and may result
                in further losses for the bank. However, in the unlikely case that the fresh credit helps the
                borrower recover, banks would get back all their debt with interest and therefore face no
                reduction in capital. Notice that the recognition of loss impacts equity holders. They get
                no return on their investments and are forced to recapitalize to maintain sufficient capital
                adequacy. In such a scenario, a capital-starved bank, where equity owners have little “skin
                in the game”, is likely to continue lending to the risky borrower. With low capital, equity
                owners have little to lose from the fresh lending in the likely scenario where the borrower
                fails. However, the unlikely case of firm revival would result in a significant upside for
                them. Depositors do not have any marginal upside in the case of risky investment but may
                incur some costs if the firm fails. Hence equity owners gain if the risks pay off and if the
                risks fail the cost would be borne by the depositors, bondholders, and/or the taxpayers.
                Forbearance further allows equity owners to restructure loans without any additional cost.
                Capital-constrained banks, therefore, choose to restructure even unviable projects when
                the opportunity arises under a forbearance regime, thereby shifting risk away from equity
                holders to depositors and taxpayers.
                The above phenomenon of forbearance-induced risk-shifting is apparent in the case of
                privately held banks where equity owners could act in their own interests. In a few Indian
                banks, promoters administer management and decision-making, directly or indirectly, by
                virtue of their controlling shareholding and/or management rights. Given their controlling
                stake,  perverse  incentives  of promoter-managers  in  the  presence  of  forbearance  are
                understandable.  However,  most  Indian  banks  are  widely  held  or  controlled  by  the
                government, and hence, their incumbent managements do not own sizeable stakes in these
                institutions. How forbearance distorts banks’ incentives in this context, therefore, needs
                an explanation. The rationale includes two key points. First, guided by their personal
                career concerns, the incumbent bank managers always have incentives to report strong
                performances during their tenure. Sarkar, Subramanian, and Tantri, 2019 show that bank
                CEOs’  post-retirement  career  benefits,  such  as  future  corporate  board  memberships,
   213   214   215   216   217   218   219   220   221   222   223